| Economic Anthropology: Past and Future | | | |
-
<< Back to editing
-
Previous version by
-
-
<< Older
-
Newer >>
-
Revert to this one
search results
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire32_3.pdf&rsargs[]=0
Andrés
Marroquín
Gramajo
Economic
Anthropology
:
Past
and
Future
Introduction
Sometimes
the
best
way
to
imagine
a
future
is
to
look
at
the
past
.
And
when
one
looks
at
the
past
of
the
research
in
economic
anthropology
,
the
future
of
the
field
looks
bright
indeed
.
The
history
of
the
this
research
reveals
that
the
types
of
themes
this
field
has
studied
during
the
past
60
years
have
expanded
.
Some
other
themes
are
permanent
and
have
defined
economic
anthropology
,
so
to
speak
.
Economic
anthropology
has
gained
its
identity
from
its
studies
of
hunter-gather
societies
,
and
the
following
transitions
to
subsistence
production
,
cash
economies
,
and
the
market
.
In
the
past
ten
years
,
the
field
witnessed
also
the
incursion
of
new
methods
,
such
as
field
experiments
.
This
suggests
that
the
themes
that
were
central
to
the
discipline
60
years
ago
will
be
studied
furthermore
in
the
near
future
;
but
also
new
,
unpredictable
topics
,
using
unexpected
methods
,
will
emerge
as
well
.
In
this
paper
I
describe
and
analyze
the
past
of
the
research
in
economic
anthropology
Andrés
Marroquín
Gramajo
is
Professor
of
Economics
,
Universidad
Francisco
Marroquín
(
Guatemala
).
This
paper
was
presented
at
the
2009
Meeting
of
the
International
Union
of
Anthropological
and
Ethnological
Sciences
(
IUAES
)
in
Kunming
,
China
,
and
will
be
published
in
the
first
number
of
the
on-line
magazine
Popular
Anthropology
.
Comments
and
suggestions
by
Julio
Cole
are
greatly
appreciated
.
Laissez-Faire
,
No
.
32
(
Marzo
2010
):
23-34
in
order
to
find
patterns
of
research
topics
through
time
and
to
speculate
about
future
themes
:
Internet
communities
,
the
phenomenon
of
religion
and
religious
diversity
,
the
cultural
aspects
of
financial
markets
,
and
the
social
implications
of
gender
differences
will
receive
more
attention
in
the
next
decade
.
Before
exploring
the
past
and
conjecturing
about
the
future
of
the
research
in
economic
anthropology
it
is
necessary
to
clarify
what
“
economic
anthropology
”
is
.
Economic
Anthropology
:
A
Definition
The
first
challenge
that
comes
up
when
one
wants
to
look
at
the
history
of
economic
anthropology
is
to
find
a
useful
definition
of
the
field
.
Dalton
considers
that
the
research
in
economic
anthropology
is
characterized
by
:
(
a
)
individual
fieldwork
,
(
b
)
a
focus
on
small
economy
(
community
),
and
(
c
)
a
consideration
of
history
.
According
to
Dalton
,
economic
anthropology
comprises
different
sets
of
topics
,
such
as
the
structure
and
performance
of
traditional
pre-colonial
,
preindustrial
,
colonial
,
and
postcolonial
tribal
and
peasant
economies
.
For
example
,
in
the
case
of
pre-colonial
societies
,
economic
anthropology
is
interested
in
the
nature
of
tribal
and
peasant
economies
before
serious
European
incursion
changed
them
;
for
instance
,
the
nature
of
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire32_3.pdf&rsargs[]=1
__________________________________________________________________
primitive
monetary
valuables
and
their
role
as
devices
of
social
control
in
the
prestige
sector
of
tribal
communities
without
central
government
(
Dalton
,
1965
:
197
).
1
Economic
anthropology
can
also
be
defined
by
the
set
of
topics
that
scholars
who
call
themselves
“
economic
anthropologists
”
write
about
;
for
example
,
the
members
of
the
Society
of
Economic
Anthropology
(
SEA
).
In
the
inaugural
meeting
of
the
Society
of
Economic
Anthropology
in
1982
participants
discussed
the
following
topics
,
among
others
:
(
1
)
history
of
pre-Hispanic
México
;
(
2
)
evolution
of
pre-Hispanic
Oaxaca
market
systems
;
(
2
)
Marx
’
s
contribution
to
economic
anthropology
;
(
3
)
the
thought
of
Karl
Polanyi
–
formalist
vs
.
substantivist
debate
;
(
4
)
problems
of
decision
making
analysis
and
complexity
in
game
theory
and
linear
programming
models
;
(
5
)
uneven
development
;
(
6
)
the
core
assumptions
of
development
economics
that
usually
do
not
take
into
account
political
roles
and
presume
a
narrow
definition
of
rationality
;
and
(
7
)
adding
social
and
cultural
elements
to
costbenefit
analysis
(
Plattner
,
1982
).
Karl
Polanyi
has
been
an
influential
figure
in
the
field
.
Although
he
was
mainly
an
economic
historian
,
his
analyses
of
preindustrial
economies
,
and
of
the
changes
that
fostered
the
industrial
revolution
itself
,
have
left
their
mark
on
economic
anthropology
.
Probably
one
of
his
most
important
insights
is
that
the
economy
is
embedded
in
society
.
This
implies
that
social
relations
(
community
,
reciprocity
,
and
fairness
)
predate
the
market
.
Polanyi
’
s
idea
follows
Aristotle
in
the
sense
that
human
beings
are
first
homo
sociologicus
and
then
acquire
characteris-
1
Concepts
like
“
primitive
”
and
“
tribal
”
are
quite
controversial
.
In
the
text
I
restrict
myself
to
the
way
Dalton
uses
those
words
.
tics
of
homo
economicus
.
One
consequence
of
this
idea
is
that
the
market
economy
(
understood
as
the
price
system
,
in
this
case
)
cannot
penetrate
all
the
spheres
of
social
life
.
There
are
realms
of
social
interaction
that
naturally
remain
outside
the
price
mechanism
(
think
of
family
relations
,
for
instance
).
In
fact
,
Polanyi
suggests
that
the
penetration
of
the
market
and
the
economy
in
noneconomic
spheres
(
consider
,
for
example
,
a
market
for
marriage
,
or
an
open
competition
for
suicide
services
)
will
face
the
opposing
response
of
social
forces
.
Imagine
a
pendulum
that
moves
left
and
right
.
The
pendulum
represents
the
degree
of
market
penetration
in
society
.
It
does
not
reach
the
extreme
right
,
but
neither
does
it
reach
the
far
left
.
Such
is
the
nature
of
the
market
imbedded
in
society
.
Social
forces
will
react
so
that
the
market
mechanism
stays
away
from
the
very
core
of
social
relations
(
see
Carlson
,
2006
,
for
a
balanced
view
of
Polanyi
’
s
contributions
).
Stephen
Gudeman
,
a
contemporary
prestigious
economic
anthropologist
,
talks
about
the
Anthropology
of
Economy
(
2001
)
where
he
contrasts
the
neoclassical
economy
and
the
economy
as
domains
of
value
.
On
the
one
hand
,
the
neoclassical
economy
refers
to
the
production
and
consumption
cycle
which
involves
firms
,
households
,
and
markets
.
The
economy
as
domains
of
value
,
on
the
other
hand
,
adds
ideology
,
identity
,
and
sacred
values
to
the
neoclassical
economy
cycle
.
Although
these
criteria
to
define
Economic
Anthropology
are
useful
,
I
should
recognize
that
this
is
a
dynamic
field
,
and
probably
it
started
“
growing
up
”
as
an
academic
discipline
since
Malinowski
’
s
times
in
the
early
1900s
.
For
the
purpose
of
clarity
I
define
__________________________________________________________________
Laissez-Faire
30
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire32_3.pdf&rsargs[]=2
__________________________________________________________________
Economic
Anthropology
as
the
intersection
of
anthropology
and
economics
.
Graphically
it
would
look
like
the
intersection
between
two
sets
(
economics
and
anthropology
)
in
a
Venn
diagram
.
This
definition
includes
using
the
tools
of
economics
to
analyze
topics
traditionally
studied
in
anthropology
,
and
using
the
tools
of
anthropology
to
study
traditional
economic
variables
(
see
this
matrix
in
Table
1
).
This
means
that
economists
who
have
studied
culture
(
Fernandez
,
2007
),
identity
(
Akerlof
and
Kranton
,
2002a
;
2002b
),
and
values
(
Porter
2000
),
2
for
example
,
are
also
considered
as
economic
anthropologists
for
the
purpose
of
analysis
.
In
some
instances
I
included
in
the
analysis
“
economic
archeology
”
as
part
of
economic
anthropology
since
both
fields
(
economic
archeology
and
economic
anthropology
)
are
closely
linked
when
it
comes
to
studying
the
economics
of
ancient
civilization
through
the
study
samples
of
material
culture
.
There
are
many
other
scientific
analyses
which
are
harder
to
classify
in
the
matrix
in
table
1
,
but
which
I
think
belong
to
economic
anthropology
.
They
come
mainly
from
economic
history
(
such
as
Botticini
and
Eckstein
,
2005
).
Some
classics
are
Karl
Polanyi
’
s
,
Max
Weber
’
s
,
and
Banfield
’
s
historical
works
(
see
for
example
Polanyi
,
1969
;
Weber
,
1958
;
and
Banfield
,
1958
).
Another
example
from
economic
history
is
David
Landes
’
s
historical
work
in
The
Wealth
and
Poverty
of
Nations
(
see
also
Landes
,
2000
),
where
he
concludes
that
“
culture
2
Obviously
Raquel
Fernandez
,
Geroge
Akerlof
,
and
Rachel
Kranton
have
done
major
work
in
areas
that
do
not
include
issues
of
culture
.
My
claim
however
is
that
the
part
of
their
work
in
which
they
do
include
culture
can
be
reasonably
included
into
the
field
of
economic
anthropology
.
makes
almost
all
the
difference
”
when
it
comes
to
explaining
historical
patterns
of
prosperity
across
the
world
.
In
this
same
category
is
Douglass
North
’
s
Institutions
,
Institutional
Change
and
Economic
Performance
.
Fukuyama
’
s
Trust
and
Robert
Putnam
’
s
Making
Democracy
Work
could
also
be
classified
as
works
on
economic
anthropology
.
Landes
and
North
are
economic
historians
,
Fukuyama
is
a
political
scientist
,
and
Putman
is
a
sociologist
.
All
of
them
study
institutions
or
civic
values
that
characterize
different
societies
,
and
some
of
these
values
have
a
direct
or
indirect
impact
on
economic
development
and
growth
.
Landes
and
North
combine
history
,
economics
,
and
culture
to
explain
variations
in
prosperity
around
the
world
.
Clearly
their
approach
is
multidisciplinary
.
Indeed
,
interdisciplinary
research
is
an
intrinsic
characteristic
of
economic
anthropology
.
There
are
other
pieces
by
North
that
I
would
not
include
into
the
realm
of
economic
anthropology
(
although
they
are
base
on
anthropological
evidence
in
some
instances
),
such
as
his
research
on
the
transition
from
nomad
societies
into
agricultural
societies
,
and
the
transition
from
agricultural
to
industrial
societies
(
North
and
Thomas
,
1977
;
1970
).
In
these
cases
he
studies
social
and
economic
transformations
using
a
utility
maximization
approach
representative
of
neo-classical
economics
.
Elinor
Ostrom
,
the
winner
of
the
2009
Nobel
Prize
,
has
also
used
different
approaches
to
study
how
culture
and
institutions
can
promote
the
sustainable
use
of
common
pool
resources
.
Ostrom
is
one
of
the
most
eclectic
social
scientists
in
terms
of
her
methods
.
She
is
driven
by
the
questions
and
not
by
the
method
,
this
makes
her
work
fascinating
although
very
hard
to
classify
in
the
matrix
below
.
In
addition
,
there
is
work
done
by
__________________________________________________________________
Laissez-Faire
31
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire32_3.pdf&rsargs[]=3
__________________________________________________________________
Table
1
.
What
is
economic
anthropology
?
An
intersection
between
concepts
and
methods
.
Conceptually
Method
of
Analysis
Economics
(
game
theory
,
econometrics
,
experiments
,
or
mathematical
modeling
)
Anthropology
(
ethnographic
)
Economics
(
the
main
purpose
is
to
study
the
economy
)
Purely
economics
(
e
.
g
.
the
interest
premium
puzzle
,
elasticity
of
the
demand
for
money
.
See
for
example
the
work
of
Barro
and
Jin
(
2009
)).
Economic
anthropology
(
e
.
g
.
Ronald
Coase
(
1937
),
Geertz
(
1978
),
Jean
Ensminger
(
1996
),
Chamlee-Wright
(
1997
),
Marroquin
(
2007
,
2008
,
2010
)).
Anthropology
(
the
main
purpose
is
to
study
culture
and
identity
)
Economic
Anthropology
(
e
.
g
.
crosscultural
experiments
to
study
altruism
and
reciprocity
,
neoclassical
economic
models
to
study
time
allocation
in
huntergather
societies
,
game
theory
to
study
evolution
of
institutions
.
See
for
example
Bates
(
1983
),
Grief
(
1994
),
Conley
and
Udry
(
2008
),
Smith
(
1975
),
Fernandez
(
2007
),
Chen
and
Li
(
2009
),
Bowles
(
1998
),
Bisin
and
Verdier
(
2000
;
2001
).
Purely
anthropology
(
e
.
g
.
certain
rites
of
passage
studied
through
participant
observation
(
Levi-
Strauss
(
1955
,
1966
,
1983
),
Geertz
(
2000
)).
__________________________________________________________________
Laissez-Faire
32
|
|