| Huerta de Soto's concerted expansion: a prisoner's dilemma in free banking | | | |
-
<< Back to editing
-
Previous version by
-
-
<< Older
-
Newer >>
-
Revert to this one
search results
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF 38.1.pdf&rsargs[]=0
__________________________________________________________________
Nicolás
Cachanosky
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
Concerted
Expansion
:
A
Prisoner
’
s
Dilemma
in
Free
Banking
?
Introduction
Concerted
expansion
is
a
common
concern
present
in
discussions
about
free
banking
performance
.
Huerta
de
Soto
(
2012
[
1998
],
pp
.
664
–
71
)
uses
game
theory
to
show
that
banks
have
incentives
to
collude
and
expand
fiduciary
media
.
According
to
Huerta
de
Soto
,
his
game
illustrates
that
incentives
exist
for
banks
to
over-expand
to
the
point
that
a
crisis
unfolds
.
His
approach
,
however
,
does
not
accurately
describe
the
problem
of
concerted
expansion
in
free
banking
.
Van
den
Hauwe
(
2008
)
critically
discusses
the
general
use
of
the
prisoner
’
s
dilemma
in
the
free
banking
literature
.
The
following
commentary
discusses
seven
specific
limitations
to
applying
the
prisoner
’
s
dilemma
model
to
concerted
expansion
in
free
banking
.
The
critical
discussion
of
these
points
also
helps
to
focus
on
relevant
challenges
for
concerted
expansion
that
are
not
clearly
present
in
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
treatment
.
Nicolás
Cachanosky
(
Ph
.
D
.,
Suffolk
University
,
2012
)
is
Assistant
Professor
of
Economics
at
Metropolitan
State
University
of
Denver
(
USA
).
The
author
would
like
to
thank
Benjamin
Powell
and
Adrián
Ravier
for
helpful
comments
.
He
is
solely
responsible
for
any
errors
or
omissions
.
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
Use
of
Game
Theory
in
Concerted
Expansion
In
Money
,
Bank
Credit
,
and
Economic
Cycles
(
2012
[
1998
]),
Huerta
de
Soto
defends
the
100
percent
rule
for
banking
reserves
.
There
are
two
lines
of
argument
for
the
convenience
of
forbidding
fractional
reserves
in
banking
.
The
first
of
these
is
drawn
from
what
Huerta
de
Soto
refers
to
as
“
traditional
legal
principles
”
that
he
traces
back
to
the
Roman
Empire
.
According
to
this
position
,
the
fractional
reserve
practice
contradicts
basic
legal
principles
by
(
1
)
lacking
a
specific
term
or
maturity
date
,
which
according
to
Huerta
de
Soto
(
2012
[
1998
],
pp
.
17-18
)
is
“
impossible
to
imagine
”
in
a
monetary
loan
contract
,
and
(
2
)
by
the
absence
of
safekeeping
of
the
deposit
.
For
Huerta
de
Soto
,
the
banker
performs
a
fraudulent
act
if
he
lends
the
deposit
for
his
own
benefit
.
Because
fractional
reserves
would
be
an
irregular
contract
,
such
practice
should
be
avoided
and
a
100
percent
rule
should
be
enforced
.
This
point
of
view
has
been
contested
by
White
(
2007
)
and
Yeager
(
2010
),
who
argue
that
such
outdated
terminology
and
legal
practices
are
inappropriate
for
an
analysis
of
contemporary
banking
and
financial
practices
.
The
second
line
of
argument
,
constructed
from
the
first
one
,
pertains
to
the
Laissez-Faire
,
No
.
38-39
(
Marzo-Sept
2013
):
1-6
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF 38.1.pdf&rsargs[]=1
__________________________________________________________________
Bank
A
Does
not
expand
Expands
Bank
B
Does
not
expand
Expands
The
survival
of
both
(
reduced
profits
)
The
failure
of
B
The
survival
of
A
The
failure
of
A
The
survival
of
B
Large
profits
for
both
instability
of
fractional
reserves
.
An
economic
crisis
may
come
in
two
forms
:
(
a
)
a
crisis
as
described
by
the
Austrian
business
cycle
theory
,
or
(
b
)
a
crisis
caused
by
a
bank
run
that
provokes
bankruptcy
and
financial
instability
.
Huerta
de
Soto
(
2012
[
1998
],
p
.
665
)
acknowledges
that
any
bank
that
expands
its
credit
faster
than
its
competitors
will
see
its
reserves
drop
quickly
.
He
continues
,
however
,
arguing
as
follows
:
Not
only
is
fractional-reserve
freebanking
incapable
of
avoiding
credit
expansion
and
the
appearance
of
cycles
,
but
it
actually
tempts
bankers
in
general
to
expand
their
loans
,
and
the
result
is
a
policy
in
which
all
bankers
,
to
one
extent
or
another
,
are
carried
away
by
optimism
in
the
granting
of
loans
and
in
the
creation
of
deposits
.
It
is
a
well-known
fact
that
whenever
property
rights
are
not
adequately
defined
—
and
this
is
the
case
with
fractional-reserve
banking
,
which
by
definition
involves
the
violation
of
depositors
’
traditional
property
rights
—
the
“
tragedy
of
the
commons
”
effect
tends
to
appear
.
Thus
a
banker
who
expands
his
loans
brings
in
a
handsome
,
and
larger
,
profit
(
if
his
bank
does
not
fail
),
while
the
cost
of
his
irresponsible
act
is
shared
by
all
other
economic
agents
.
It
is
for
this
reason
that
bankers
face
the
almost
irresistible
temptation
to
be
the
first
to
initiate
a
policy
of
expansion
,
particularly
if
they
expect
all
other
banks
to
follow
suit
to
one
degree
or
another
,
which
often
occurs
(
pp
.
666-67
).
Huerta
de
Soto
further
asserts
that
issuer
banks
in
free
banking
are
in
a
similar
situation
to
that
of
a
tragedy
of
the
commons
,
the
difference
being
that
if
not
all
banks
expand
in
concert
then
the
mechanism
of
adverse
clearing
comes
into
play
.
He
illustrates
the
situation
with
the
table
shown
above
.
Following
his
argument
on
traditional
legal
principles
,
Huerta
de
Soto
compares
the
situation
of
free
banking
to
that
of
a
tragedy
of
the
commons
where
overexpansion
of
credit
substitutes
the
depredation
of
resources
.
Selgin
and
White
(
1996
,
pp
.
92-93
)
criticized
this
analogy
in
their
discussion
of
a
previous
article
by
Huerta
de
Soto
(
1995
,
p
.
33
).
They
argued
that
economists
“
conventionally
distinguish
a
‘
pecuniary
externality
,’
an
effort
on
someone
’
s
wealth
transmitted
via
the
price
system
,
from
a
‘
technological
externality
’,”
and
that
Huerta
de
Soto
“
fails
to
grasp
this
distinction
when
he
mischaracterizes
the
pecuniary
externality
from
fiduciary
media
as
a
‘
tragedy
of
the
commons
,’
a
term
that
properly
applies
to
a
particular
sort
of
technological
externality
.”
Huerta
de
Soto
,
however
,
defended
the
analogy
as
correct
,
arguing
that
“
the
issue
of
fiduciary
media
stems
from
the
violation
of
traditional
property
rights
in
connection
with
the
monetary
bankdeposit
contract
,
and
that
hence
fiduciary
media
are
not
a
spontaneous
phenomenon
of
a
legally
based
free-market
process
”
__________________________________________________________________
2
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF 38.1.pdf&rsargs[]=2
__________________________________________________________________
(
Huerta
de
Soto
(
2012
[
1998
],
p
.
667
).
He
concludes
that
“
it
is
obvious
that
given
the
choices
above
”
the
banks
will
“
initiate
a
joint
policy
of
credit
expansion
which
will
protect
both
from
insolvency
and
guarantee
handsome
profits
”
(
p
.
668
).
Limitations
of
the
Game
Applied
to
Concerted
Expansion
Prisoner
’
s
Dilemma
?
The
first
limitation
with
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
treatment
is
that
,
although
he
refers
to
the
game
as
one
“
typically
used
to
illustrate
both
cooperative
games
and
‘
prisoner
’
s
dilemmas
’
…
”
(
p
.
668n
),
his
presentation
does
not
correspond
to
that
of
the
prisoner
’
s
dilemma
.
1
The
latter
has
strictly
dominant
strategies
and
one
Nash
equilibrium
that
happens
to
be
sub-optimal
.
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
game
equilibrium
,
on
the
other
hand
,
is
Pareto
efficient
because
the
banks
collude
to
seize
large
profits
for
both
.
The
situation
that
the
banks
face
in
the
presented
form
thus
does
not
resemble
the
problem
in
a
conventional
prisoner
’
s
dilemma
.
On
the
contrary
,
in
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
treatment
the
players
collude
in
the
Pareto
efficient
equilibrium
.
The
concerted
expansion
becomes
not
a
dilemma
,
but
the
best
outcome
for
the
banks
given
the
structure
of
the
presented
game
.
Repeated
Game
The
second
limitation
is
that
Huerta
de
Soto
presents
the
game
as
a
one-move
game
.
The
conclusion
that
a
central
bank
will
finally
appear
is
not
deduced
from
1
Note
that
in
the
2009
Spanish
edition
this
reference
to
cooperation
games
and
prisoner
’
s
dilemmas
is
absent
.
the
game
itself
but
must
be
assumed
and
then
added
to
the
end
of
the
game
.
Although
Huerta
de
Soto
argues
that
colluding
banks
and
central
banks
are
designed
to
“
orchestrate
”
and
“
organize
”
concerted
expansion
,
the
non-repetitive
aspect
of
the
game
does
not
describe
the
concerted
expansion
problem
before
the
central
bank
is
created
.
This
is
a
relevant
point
since
the
problem
of
the
prisoner
’
s
dilemma
vanishes
in
the
case
of
repeated
games
.
Certainly
banks
are
reviewing
their
decisions
frequently
,
and
therefore
a
repeated
game
is
a
more
appropriate
assumption
than
a
non-repeated
game
.
Barriers
to
Entry
The
third
limitation
has
to
do
with
the
lack
of
room
in
the
game
for
new
competitors
to
join
the
market
when
colluded
expansion
raises
income
.
If
collusion
were
to
yield
significant
returns
,
as
assumed
,
then
it
should
then
attract
new
competitors
into
the
banking
sector
.
Without
such
a
possibility
,
the
game
can
hardly
be
considered
an
accurate
description
of
the
free
banking
scenario
.
Although
Huerta
de
Soto
(
2012
[
1998
],
pp
.
669
–
670
)
touches
on
this
point
,
he
concludes
that
central
banks
“
generally
appear
as
a
result
of
requests
from
private
bankers
”
so
that
“
the
‘
uncooperative
’
behavior
of
a
significant
number
of
relatively
more
prudent
bankers
is
prevented
from
endangering
the
solvency
of
the
rest
.”
In
other
words
,
he
argues
that
collusion
becomes
stable
because
colluding
banks
promote
the
ultimate
appearance
of
a
central
bank
to
institutionalize
the
joint
credit
expansion
.
But
the
need
and
presence
of
a
central
bank
cannot
be
an
argument
that
free
banking
is
unstable
since
the
collusion
strategy
is
selfdefeating
just
as
the
free-banking
literature
argues
.
Colluding
banks
are
unable
__________________________________________________________________
3
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF 38.1.pdf&rsargs[]=3
__________________________________________________________________
to
survive
competition
absent
the
protection
of
a
central
bank
.
How
is
that
a
valid
argument
against
free
banking
?
Solvency
and
Goodwill
The
fourth
limitation
is
related
to
solvency
and
goodwill
considerations
.
This
problem
was
mentioned
by
Mises
(
1996
[
1949
],
Chap
.
12
),
a
reference
that
Huerta
de
Soto
quotes
(
p
.
665
)
but
a
problem
that
he
fails
to
address
.
Mises
points
out
that
solvency
considerations
will
constrain
issuer
banks
from
colluding
with
less
efficient
banks
(
Mises
,
1996
[
1949
],
p
.
441
).
A
bank
,
argues
Mises
,
puts
too
much
at
risk
by
joining
a
venture
with
a
low
goodwill
partner
.
Building
goodwill
is
a
difficult
and
long-term
task
for
banks
that
can
easily
be
lost
setting
the
stage
for
bankruptcy
.
According
to
Mises
:
But
,
some
people
may
ask
,
what
about
a
cartel
of
the
commercial
banks
?
Could
not
the
banks
collude
for
the
sake
of
a
boundless
expansion
of
their
issuance
of
fiduciary
media
?
The
objection
is
preposterous
.
As
long
as
the
public
is
not
,
by
government
interference
,
deprived
of
the
right
of
withdrawing
its
deposits
,
no
bank
can
risk
its
own
good
will
by
collusion
with
banks
whose
good
will
is
not
as
high
as
its
own
.
One
must
not
forget
that
every
bank
issuing
fiduciary
media
is
in
a
rather
precarious
position
.
Its
most
valuable
asset
is
its
reputation
.
It
must
go
bankrupt
as
soon
as
doubts
arise
concerning
its
perfect
trustworthiness
and
solvency
.
It
would
be
suicidal
for
a
bank
of
good
standing
to
link
its
name
with
that
of
other
banks
with
a
poorer
good
will
.
Under
free
banking
a
cartel
of
the
banks
would
destroy
the
country
’
s
whole
banking
system
.
It
would
not
serve
the
interests
of
any
bank
(
Mises
,
1996
[
1949
],
p
.
447
,
italics
added
).
Independently
of
the
validity
of
Mises
’
assessment
of
solvency
and
goodwill
,
the
game
as
applied
to
free
banking
does
not
deal
with
the
problem
of
differences
in
solvency
and
goodwill
;
it
merely
assumes
these
problems
away
.
Volatility
of
Reserves
The
fifth
limitation
is
the
impact
of
the
variance
of
reserves
when
fiduciary
media
is
expanded
on
the
behavior
of
banks
,
an
issue
that
has
been
pointed
out
by
Selgin
(
1988
,
pp
.
80
–
82
;
1994
).
Selgin
’
s
point
is
also
not
addressed
by
Huerta
de
Soto
,
despite
the
facts
that
Selgin
’
s
argument
was
made
ten
years
prior
to
the
first
edition
of
Huerta
de
Soto
’
s
book
,
and
that
Huerta
de
Soto
actually
quotes
Selgin
’
s
(
1994
)
discussion
on
the
effect
of
the
variance
of
reserves
on
page
670
(
footnote
98
).
Selgin
draws
attention
to
the
fact
that
under
concerted
expansion
,
even
if
the
expected
reserve
value
remains
unchanged
,
reserve
’
s
variance
will
increase
,
which
,
as
a
risk
measure
,
will
require
the
banks
to
increase
their
precautionary
reserve
holdings
.
Selgin
recognizes
that
some
concerted
expansion
may
occur
if
the
proportional
change
in
the
variance
of
reserves
is
smaller
than
the
proportional
change
of
the
fiduciary
media
.
According
to
Selgin
(
1988
,
pp
.
82
):
Under
in-concerted
expansion
no
member
of
a
system
of
banks
expanding
in
unison
(
and
in
the
face
of
an
unchanged
demand
for
money
)
will
experience
any
increase
in
its
average
net
reserve
demand
;
the
change
in
expected
value
of
its
clearing
debits
.
But
the
growth
in
total
clearings
will
bring
about
a
growth
(
though
perhaps
less
than
proportionate
)
in
the
variance
of
clearing
debit
and
credits
,
which
increases
the
precautionary
reserve
needs
of
every
bank
.
Thus
,
given
the
quantity
of
reserve
media
,
the
demand
for
and
turnover
of
inside
money
,
and
the
desire
of
banks
to
protect
themselves
against
all
but
a
very
small
risk
of
default
at
the
__________________________________________________________________
4
|
|