| Towards a Microeconomic Theory of the Finance-driven Business Cycle | | | |
-
<< Back to editing
-
Previous version by
-
-
<< Older
-
Newer >>
-
Revert to this one
search results
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF-42.2 Jenkins.pdf&rsargs[]=0
__________________________________________________________________
Alejandro
Jenkins
Towards
a
Microeconomic
Theory
of
the
Finance-driven
Business
Cycle
Introduction
The
business
cycle
is
the
recurrence
of
large
macroeconomic
fluctuations
about
the
long-term
growth
trend
in
a
market
economy
.
Understanding
this
phenomenon
is
a
central
and
longstanding
problem
in
economic
theory
.
It
is
also
a
question
of
great
political
significance
in
the
modern
world
.
Finance
fulfills
the
useful
function
of
transferring
the
control
of
capital
from
those
who
own
it
to
those
who
can
put
it
to
productive
use
.
The
vastly
higher
standard
of
living
of
industrialized
countries
compared
to
more
traditional
societies
would
be
impossible
without
private
finance
.
There
is
,
however
,
a
widespread
and
longstanding
sense
that
the
most
severe
fluctuations
in
free
market
economies
are
driven
by
an
instability
associated
with
financial
speculation
.
1
1
M
.
Weber
,
General
Economic
History
,
trans
.
F
.
H
.
Knight
(
Mineola
,
NY
:
Dover
,
2003
[
1923
]),
Chapter
XXIV
.
Alejandro
Jenkins
(
Ph
.
D
.,
Caltech
,
2006
;
A
.
B
.,
Harvard
,
2001
)
is
a
member
of
Costa
Rica
’
s
National
Academy
of
Sciences
.
He
is
currently
an
invited
professor
at
the
University
of
Costa
Rica
’
s
physics
department
.
In
the
past
he
has
worked
as
a
research
associate
at
Caltech
,
MIT
,
and
Florida
State
University
.
The
evidence
of
business
cycles
is
clear
,
but
the
phenomenon
has
proved
challenging
to
comprehend
theoretically
.
One
reason
is
that
,
if
applicable
,
the
microeconomic
equilibrium
theorems
would
rule
out
the
kind
of
miscoordination
between
economic
agents
that
seems
to
mark
the
most
severe
crises
.
Those
theorems
assume
that
markets
are
complete
(
so
that
all
possible
voluntary
transactions
can
be
carried
out
)
and
that
all
agents
enjoy
perfect
information
.
2
Those
conditions
are
obviously
not
achieved
in
practice
,
but
markets
usually
equilibrate
quite
well
under
more
realistic
circumstances
,
both
in
the
real
world
and
in
controlled
experiments
.
3
Some
macroeconomic
fluctuations
are
undoubtedly
caused
by
the
market
‟
s
response
to
exogenous
shocks
.
4
Credit
re-
2
K
.
J
.
Arrow
,
“
An
Extension
of
the
Basic
Theorems
of
Classical
Welfare
Economics
,”
Proceedings
of
the
Second
Berkeley
Symposium
on
Mathematical
Statistics
and
Probability
(
Berkeley
:
University
of
California
Press
,
1951
),
pp
.
507-532
;
G
.
Debreu
,
Theory
of
Value
(
New
Haven
:
Yale
University
Press
,
1987
[
1959
]).
3
V
.
L
.
Smith
,
Rationality
in
Economics
(
Cambridge
:
Cambridge
University
Press
,
2008
).
4
R
.
E
.
Lucas
,
Jr
.,
Models
of
Business
Cycles
Laissez-Faire
,
No
.
42
(
Marzo
2015
):
12-20
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF-42.2 Jenkins.pdf&rsargs[]=1
__________________________________________________________________
strictions
can
amplify
the
effects
of
such
shocks
,
5
but
even
then
the
welfare
cost
of
the
fluctuations
might
be
insufficient
to
justify
interventionist
stabilization
policies
.
6
On
the
other
hand
,
the
largest
of
the
macroeconomic
fluctuations
associated
with
episodes
of
financial
panic
followed
by
high
unemployment
and
political
disturbances
seem
to
be
endogenous
and
inefficient
.
In
order
to
understand
what
could
drive
such
fluctuations
,
and
how
to
alleviate
them
,
it
is
necessary
to
understand
just
why
and
how
financial
markets
may
sometimes
fail
to
equilibrate
.
Here
I
shall
sketch
,
in
broad
outline
,
a
program
for
a
microeconomic
theory
of
the
business
cycle
,
i
.
e
.,
for
an
understanding
based
on
the
choices
made
by
rational
agents
.
In
this
view
,
the
business
cycle
,
or
at
least
a
major
component
of
it
,
appears
as
a
recurring
market
inefficiency
driven
by
incompleteness
of
financial
markets
and
by
information
asymmetries
between
borrowers
and
lenders
.
This
proposal
brings
together
five
distinguishable
but
connected
processes
.
Previous
researchers
have
treated
each
of
these
,
though
,
to
my
knowledge
,
they
have
not
articulated
them
as
a
coherent
theoretical
framework
for
the
business
cycle
as
a
whole
.
These
processes
are
:
(
1
)
the
leverage
cycle
,
(
2
)
financial
panic
,
(
3
)
debt
deflation
,
(
4
)
debt
overhang
,
and
(
5
)
deleveraging
of
households
.
(
New
York
:
Basil
Blackwell
,
1987
).
The
application
to
the
business
cycle
of
ideas
taken
from
the
mathematical
sciences
of
control
theory
,
non-linear
dynamics
,
and
non-equilibrium
thermodynamics
has
a
long
but
not
very
fruitful
history
.
7
I
believe
that
the
basic
shortcoming
of
such
efforts
has
been
the
absence
of
an
adequate
microeconomic
foundation
,
which
is
what
a
physical
scientist
is
least
likely
to
contribute
.
I
have
nonetheless
been
motivated
to
draw
up
this
“
memorandum
”
by
the
sense
that
the
separate
strands
of
what
could
be
a
satisfactory
understanding
of
the
financedriven
business
cycle
exist
already
,
but
are
not
being
drawn
together
in
a
wholly
satisfactory
way
by
economists
.
Moreover
,
the
policy
implications
of
such
a
theory
could
be
significant
,
but
I
have
not
seen
them
clearly
articulated
in
the
public
debates
that
have
followed
the
financial
crisis
of
2007-08
.
Of
existing
strands
of
macroeconomic
thought
,
the
most
relevant
to
this
work
is
traceable
to
Irving
Fisher
(
1867-1947
),
the
first
theorist
to
stress
that
debt
need
not
be
macroeconomically
neutral
.
8
Hyman
Minsky
has
pursued
this
idea
within
a
post-Keynesian
framework
.
9
More
recently
,
Claudio
Borio
has
proposed
a
“
financial
cycle
”
as
the
driver
of
the
big-
7
For
a
review
of
the
relevant
literature
,
and
some
earlier
comments
of
my
own
on
the
business
cycle
,
see
A
.
Jenkins
,
“
Selfoscillation
,”
Physics
Reports
,
525
(
2013
):
167-222
.
5
N
.
Kiyotaki
and
J
.
Moore
,
“
Credit
Cycles
,”
Journal
of
Political
Economy
,
105
(
1997
):
211-248
.
6
P
.
Krusell
et
al
.,
“
Revisiting
the
Welfare
Effects
of
Eliminating
Business
Cycles
,”
Review
of
Economic
Dynamics
,
12
(
2009
):
8
J
.
Tobin
,
“
Irving
Fisher
(
1867-1947
),”
in
J
.
Eatwell
,
J
.
M
.
Milgate
and
P
.
Newman
(
eds
.),
New
Palgrave
Dictionary
of
Economics
(
London
:
Macmillan
,
1987
),
vol
.
2
,
pp
.
369-
376
.
9
H
.
Minsky
,
Stabilizing
an
Unstable
Econo-
393-404
.
my
(
New
York
:
McGraw-Hill
,
2008
[
1986
]).
__________________________________________________________________
13
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF-42.2 Jenkins.pdf&rsargs[]=2
__________________________________________________________________
gest
macroeconomic
fluctuations
.
10
Steven
Gjerstad
and
Vernon
Smith
(
who
have
had
the
most
direct
influence
on
my
own
thinking
)
have
explored
similar
ideas
,
with
a
particular
focus
on
residential
mortgages
.
11
Leverage
Cycle
It
is
widely
recognized
that
asset
markets
(
in
which
the
same
good
may
be
purchased
and
sold
many
times
)
are
susceptible
to
speculative
bubbles
,
in
which
prices
rise
well
above
the
fundamentals
because
of
a
self-reinforcing
but
finally
unsustainable
expectation
that
prices
will
continue
to
rise
.
This
process
ends
with
a
rapid
collapse
of
the
asset
price
.
Despite
the
widespread
recognition
that
this
phenomenon
has
recurred
throughout
history
,
the
microeconomic
theory
of
why
such
bubbles
occur
and
how
they
may
harm
the
economy
as
a
whole
remains
incomplete
and
contentious
.
That
self-reinforcing
fads
should
cause
temporary
spikes
in
the
prices
of
some
assets
may
not
require
an
explanation
much
deeper
than
the
obvious
psychological
one
.
Nothing
in
the
equilibrium
theorems
prevents
people
‟
s
preferences
from
changing
over
time
.
But
the
sheer
size
of
certain
speculative
bubbles
,
and
the
serious
damage
that
they
can
cause
to
the
economy
at
large
,
pose
major
challenges
for
economic
theory
and
policy
.
10
C
.
Borio
,
“
The
Financial
Cycle
and
Macroeconomics
:
What
Have
We
Learned
?”
Journal
of
Banking
&
Finance
,
45
(
2014
):
182-
198
.
According
to
Max
Weber
‟
s
General
Economic
History
,
the
great
Mississippi
Company
bubble
of
the
late
1710s
“
can
be
explained
only
by
the
fact
that
short
selling
was
impracticable
since
there
was
as
yet
no
systematic
exchange
mechanism
.”
12
That
is
,
the
bubble
resulted
from
a
market
incompleteness
that
made
it
easier
for
optimists
than
for
pessimists
to
bet
on
future
price
changes
.
Modernly
,
the
relevant
incompleteness
probably
lies
in
the
financial
market
rather
than
the
asset
market
itself
:
it
is
usually
easier
for
optimists
than
for
pessimists
to
leverage
their
bets
(
i
.
e
.,
to
make
them
with
borrowed
money
).
As
the
price
of
an
asset
begins
to
climb
,
it
may
happen
that
it
can
be
increasingly
leveraged
.
As
leverage
increases
,
it
takes
a
smaller
up-front
payment
to
acquire
the
asset
.
The
marginal
buyer
,
who
sets
the
price
,
is
therefore
likely
to
be
more
optimistic
about
the
price
trend
,
making
the
price
higher
.
Higher
prices
make
the
asset
a
more
attractive
investment
,
justifying
optimism
and
leading
to
greater
leverage
.
This
positive
feedback
between
leverage
and
asset
price
continues
until
they
reach
unsustainable
levels
and
collapse
.
John
Geanakoplos
has
developed
a
sophisticated
model
for
this
process
.
13
Geanakoplos
points
out
that
in
the
run-up
to
the
2007-08
financial
crisis
,
credit
default
swaps
(
CDS
)
did
provide
a
mechanism
to
borrow
money
for
betting
against
the
housing
market
.
(
A
CDS
is
a
negotiable
contract
that
promises
to
compensate
the
buyer
if
some
underlying
financial
instrument
goes
into
default
.)
However
,
CDS
‟
s
became
widely
availa-
12
Weber
,
op
.
cit
.,
p
.
288
.
11
S
.
D
.
Gjerstad
and
V
.
L
.
Smith
,
Rethinking
Housing
Bubbles
(
Cambridge
:
Cambridge
13
J
.
Geanakoplos
,
“
The
Leverage
Cycle
,”
NBER
Macroeconomics
Annual
,
24
(
2010
):
University
Press
,
2014
).
1-66
.
__________________________________________________________________
14
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=LF-42.2 Jenkins.pdf&rsargs[]=3
__________________________________________________________________
ble
for
US
residential
mortgages
only
in
late
2005
,
when
the
housing
bubble
was
already
well
underway
and
approaching
its
peak
.
In
those
circumstances
,
the
introduction
of
CDS
‟
s
may
have
helped
precipitate
the
crash
.
14
A
point
worth
highlighting
is
that
the
standard
equilibrium
theorems
allow
for
differences
in
individual
preferences
,
but
not
for
differences
of
beliefs
(
e
.
g
.,
of
optimists
versus
pessimists
),
which
would
not
exist
in
a
state
of
perfect
knowledge
.
Hayek
,
Stigler
,
and
other
pioneers
of
the
economics
of
information
have
emphasized
that
,
in
the
real
world
,
economically
relevant
knowledge
is
not
a
given
,
but
rather
emerges
through
the
market
process
itself
.
15
Therefore
,
the
absence
of
CDS
‟
s
in
the
housing
market
may
have
been
significant
not
only
as
an
incompleteness
per
se
,
but
also
because
it
prevented
the
information
possessed
by
the
more
pessimistic
potential
investors
from
being
incorporated
into
the
asset
prices
in
a
timely
way
.
Financial
Panic
When
the
growth
phase
of
the
leverage
cycle
ends
with
a
rapid
decline
of
asset
prices
,
many
of
those
who
borrowed
to
purchase
the
asset
are
forced
to
default
on
their
loans
.
Since
the
now
depressed
asset
14
Ibid
.
See
also
“
Discussion
Summary
of
„
The
Leverage
Cycle
‟,”
NBER
Macroeconomics
Annual
,
24
(
2010
):
85-87
.
usually
serves
as
collateral
for
those
loans
,
lenders
suffer
serious
losses
.
Borrowers
whose
debts
are
now
worth
more
than
the
collateral
are
especially
likely
to
default
.
Furthermore
,
financial
institutions
often
hold
those
same
assets
in
their
balance
sheets
.
They
are
therefore
suddenly
faced
with
large
accounting
shortfalls
and
acute
uncertainty
about
their
ability
to
meet
their
obligations
.
A
panic
ensues
in
which
other
lenders
(
e
.
g
.,
ordinary
bank
depositors
)
withdraw
their
funds
and
financial
institutions
are
forced
to
liquidate
assets
at
“
fire
sale
”
prices
,
further
depressing
their
market
value
.
Many
financial
institutions
may
become
illiquid
and
the
financial
sector
as
a
whole
may
cease
to
function
properly
,
doing
immediate
harm
to
the
real
economy
.
16
Such
a
financial
panic
may
be
either
alleviated
or
aggravated
by
financial
regulations
and
government
interventions
.
Since
the
early
20
th
century
,
it
has
been
widely
accepted
that
one
of
the
key
roles
of
central
banks
is
to
act
as
lender
of
last
resort
,
providing
liquidity
to
distressed
financial
institutions
that
are
actually
solvent
.
17
Nonetheless
,
some
questions
remain
about
how
best
to
implement
this
in
practice
.
It
may
be
difficult
for
the
lender
of
last
resort
,
in
the
midst
of
a
panic
,
to
make
fully
rational
decisions
about
which
distressed
institutions
are
merely
illiquid
(
so
that
loans
are
likely
to
be
re-
16
S
.
Gjerstad
and
V
.
L
.
Smith
,
“
Monetary
Policy
,
Credit
Extension
,
and
Housing
Bubbles
:
2008
and
1929
,”
Critical
Review
,
29
(
2009
):
269-300
.
17
B
.
S
.
Bernanke
,
“
Some
Reflections
on
the
Crisis
and
the
Policy
Response
”
(
speech
before
the
Russell
Sage
Foundation
and
The
Century
Foundation
Conference
on
“
Rethinking
Finance
”,
New
York
,
April
13
,
2012
)
(
http
://
www
.
federalreserve
.
gov
/
newsevents
/
s
15
F
.
A
.
Hayek
,
“
Economics
and
Knowledge
,”
in
Individualism
and
Economic
Order
(
Chicago
:
University
of
Chicago
Press
,
1948
),
pp
.
33-56
;
G
.
J
.
Stigler
,
“
The
Economics
of
Information
,”
Journal
of
Political
Economy
,
69
(
1961
):
213-225
and
“
Imperfections
in
the
Capital
Market
,”
Journal
of
Political
Economy
,
75
(
1967
):
287-292
.
See
also
Smith
,
Rationality
in
Economics
,
pp
.
61-68
.
peech
/
bernanke20120413a
.
htm
).
__________________________________________________________________
15
|
|