| Towards a Dynamic Microeconomics | | | |
-
<< Back to editing
-
Previous version by
-
-
<< Older
-
Newer >>
-
Revert to this one
search results
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire05_1_.pdf&rsargs[]=0
Antal
E
.
Fekete
Towards
a
Dynaimic
Microeconomics
Introduction
Alan
Meltzer
has
once
remarked
that
"
we
need
a
dynamic
micro-theory
"
.
The
static
supply
/
demand
equihbrium
analysis
of
pnce
formation
is
one-dimensional
.
It
looks
at
the
product
in
total
isolation
.
It
admits
no
insight
into
the
effect
on
the
price
of
altemative
products
,
either
at
the
input
or
at
the
output
end
of
the
production
line
.
It
makes
no
allowance
for
delibérate
variation
in
product
quality
on
the
part
of
the
producer
.
A
dynamic
theory
of
price
formation
would
have
to
be
three-dimaisional
.
It
would
have
to
take
the
inter-dependence
of
the
price
with
those
of
substitutes
at
both
the
input
and
the
output
level
into
full
account
.
It
would
have
to
allow
for
delibérate
variation
in
product
quality
.
In
the
present
paper
we
attempt
to
lay
the
foundations
of
such
a
dynamic
theory
,
explicitly
recognizing
arbitrage
as
the
driving
forcé
of
the
market
process
.
We
shall
use
the
language
of
traders
with
daily
experience
with
arbitrage
.
Their
guiding
star
is
the
spread
.
the
difference
in
price
between
two
goods
(
baskets
of
goods
or
,
even
more
generally
,
baskets
of
goods
and
other
resources
).
Their
basic
tool
is
the
straddle
.
the
combination
of
a
purchase
and
a
sale
.
The
arbitrageur
is
shuffling
his
straddles
in
pursuit
of
puré
oitrepreneurial
profit
.
To
the
uninitiated
it
looks
as
if
he
is
guided
by
intuition
.
But
theory
can
establish
the
basic
facts
goveming
arbitrage
without
appealing
to
intuition
.
The
marginal
analysis
of
price
formation
of
consumer
goods
to
be
presented
here
isolates
three
types
of
arbitrage
:
(
1
)
the
horizontal
arbitrage
of
the
consumer
,
responsible
for
the
formation
of
the
asked
price
,
usmg
one-legged
straddles
;
(
2
)
the
vertical
arbitrage
of
the
producer
,
responsible
for
the
formation
of
the
bid
price
,
using
two-l^ged
straddles
;
and
(
3
)
the
bid
/
asked
arbitrage
of
the
market-maker
,
responsible
for
closing
the
bid
/
asked
spread
.
In
the
second
part
of
the
paper
we
discuss
problems
of
entreproieurship
and
profit
in
the
light
of
arbitrage
.
Horizontal
arbitrage
has
a
role
to
play
in
retrospective
strat^es
to
protect
profítability
,
including
variation
of
product
quality
and
increasing
capacity
utilization
.
Vertical
arbitrage
using
four-legged
straddles
has
a
role
to
play
in
Antal
E
.
Fekete
,
Professor
Emeñtus
,
Memorial
University
of
Newfoundland
,
was
Visiting
Professor
of
Economics
at
Universidad
Francisco
Marroquín
during
1996
.
He
is
the
author
of
several
monographs
and
papers
on
monetary
reform
,
and
was
recently
the
winner
of
the
International
Currency
Prize
for
1996
,
awarded
by
Bank
Lips
,
Ltd
.
(
Zürich
).
His
e-mail
address
is
:
fekete
@nemann
.
math
.
mun
.
ca
.
Laissez
-
Faire
1
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire05_1_.pdf&rsargs[]=1
prospective
,
forward-looking
strat^es
of
aggressively
pursuing
puré
entrepreneurial
profít
.
Entrqjraieurial
success
depaids
on
the
skill
to
mesh
these
strategies
.
This
paper
is
the
fírst
in
a
series
.
Much
work
remains
to
be
done
to
deal
with
other
types
of
arbitrage
,
such
as
inter-spatial
and
inter-temporal
arbitrage
having
important
implications
in
regard
to
tnter-regional
and
intemational
trade
and
the
formation
of
futures
prices
,
and
also
arbitrage
between
the
bond
market
and
other
markets
,
having
important
implications
in
r^ard
to
the
formation
of
the
interest
rate
structure
.
These
and
other
related
issues
will
be
dealt
with
in
subsequent
papers
.
Arbitrage
Arbitrage
is
the
driving
forcé
of
the
market
process
.
It
is
present
in
every
market
action
,
even
though
sometimes
it
may
well
be
hidden
.
It
is
not
often
recognized
that
barter
—
a
sale
and
a
purchase
'telescoped'
into
a
single
transaction
—
is
an
instance
of
arbitrage
.
By
the
same
token
so
is
every
purchase
,
since
an
explicit
choice
always
incorporates
the
implicit
rejection
of
the
nearest
altemative
.
The
word
'arbitrage'
is
used
in
this
paper
in
its
broadest
possible
sense
,
in
order
to
unify
the
seemingly
fragmented
activities
of
entrepreneurs
and
the
seemingly
unrelated
sources
of
puré
entrepreneurial
profit
.
Arbitrage
is
a
market
strat^y
that
puts
the
emphasis
not
on
sales
per
se
but
on
straddles
,
and
is
motivated
not
by
prices
per
se
,
but
by
spreads
.
A
straddle
is
a
market
position
with
a
long
and
a
short
leg
.
The
long
leg
could
be
an
outright
purchase
but
,
more
typically
,
it
is
a
commitment
to
buy
or
,
just
as
typically
,
the
liquidation
of
a
commitment
to
sell
.
The
short
leg
could
be
an
outright
sale
but
,
again
,
more
typically
it
is
a
commitmait
to
sell
,
or
the
liquidation
of
a
commitmait
to
buy
.
The
commitment
to
buy
or
sell
(
or
the
liquidation
thereof
)
is
always
made
at
the
current
price
.
To
every
straddle
there
belongs
a
spread
,
that
is
,
the
difference
between
the
prices
at
which
the
commitments
to
buy
and
sell
have
beai
made
(
sale
price
less
purchase
price
).
The
spread
,
like
the
price
,
is
subject
to
change
.
But
the
information-contait
of
a
change
in
the
spread
,
unlike
that
in
the
price
,
is
highly
signifícant
.
In
fact
the
importance
of
arbitrage
,
and
the
reason
why
human
action
should
be
viewed
from
the
vantage
point
of
the
spread
,
rather
than
from
that
of
the
price
,
is
found
in
the
fact
that
a
single
move
in
the
price
is
mostly
random
.
By
contrast
,
a
single
move
of
the
spread
(
in
a
well-traded
market
)
is
a
signal
that
is
far
from
being
random
.
The
knowledgeable
arbitrageur
can
read
it
make
most
of
it
.
and
This
insight
of
his
is
the
true
source
of
puré
entrepreneurial
profit
.
Our
starting
point
is
the
fundamaital
observation
of
Cari
Menger
in
Principies
of
Economics
that
markets
do
not
quote
one
single
monolithic
price
;
they
in
fact
quote
two
prices
:
a
higher
and
a
lower
one
.
In
market
parlance
,
the
higher
one
is
called
the
asked
price
,
and
the
lower
the
bid
price
.
The
two
are
never
equal
,
so
that
the
bid
/
asked
spread
(
i
.
e
.,
asked
minus
bid
price
)
is
always
positive
.
The
fundamental
question
to
ask
is
how
the
bid
and
asked
prices
are
formed
by
the
market
process
.
We
shall
see
that
the
asked
price
is
the
outcome
of
the
competition
of
the
consumers
,
while
the
bid
price
is
the
outcome
of
the
competition
of
the
producers
.
Either
process
can
be
described
as
arbitrage
,
addressing
a
definite
spread
,
using
a
deñnite
type
of
straddle
.
Laissez
-
Paire
2
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire05_1_.pdf&rsargs[]=2
The
four-legged
straddle
When
the
arbitrageur
sees
a
profitable
spread
,
say
,
he
fínds
the
p
rice
of
one
item
X
too
low
while
that
of
a
related
item
y
too
high
,
he
sets
up
his
initial
straddle
consisting
of
the
initial
long
leg
(
commitment
to
buy
x
)
and
the
initial
short
leg
(
commitment
to
sell
y
)
at
the
prevaihng
pnces
.
In
market
parlance
,
he
has
entered
one
market
with
the
long
1^
and
another
with
the
short
.
The
arbitrageur
expects
his
spread
to
widen
(
narrow
in
absolute
valué
,
if
n^ative
).
If
the
market
moves
in
his
favor
,
he
takes
prqfit
by
ofFsetting
his
straddle
:
he
enters
the
same
markets
once
more
but
with
the
long
and
short
legs
switched
around
.
Thus
his
opposite
straddle
consists
of
the
terminal
short
leg
(
liquidating
the
commitment
to
buy
x
)
and
the
terminal
long
leg
(
liquidating
the
commitment
to
sell
y
)
at
the
new
pnces
.
His
profit
is
the
net
change
in
the
spread
(
terminal
minus
initial
spread
;
if
negative
,
he
has
made
a
loss
).
We
refer
to
this
as
a
four-legged
straddle
,
as
the
profit
from
the
arbitrage
can
be
calculated
only
after
all
four
l^s
are
in
place
.
in
place
,
this
is
a
four-l^ged
straddle
.
The
foreign
exchange
trader's
basic
tool
is
also
the
four-l^ged
straddle
.
This
is
not
surprising
if
we
contémplate
that
his
business
also
has
the
characteristic
of
warehousing
.
To
catch
a
glimpse
of
the
true
significance
of
the
four-l^ged
straddle
consider
the
fact
that
the
volume
of
the
world's
foreign
exchange
markets
is
estimated
at
a
mind-boggling
one
and
one
quarter
trillion
doUars
per
doy
,
more
than
the
annual
budget
of
the
U
.
S
.
govemment
.
Virtually
all
of
this
trading
is
hedged
,
that
is
,
done
through
the
vehicle
of
four-legged
straddles
.
But
the
importance
of
the
four-legged
straddle
goes
beyond
the
range
of
these
examples
.
Every
type
of
arbitrage
can
be
reduced
to
four-legged
straddles
.
Note
that
the
four-l^ged
straddles
above
are
special
in
that
the
terminal
l^s
liquidate
the
respective
commitments
made
by
the
initial
l^s
.
In
the
general
case
this
restriction
is
removed
.
In
the
second
part
of
this
paper
we
shall
see
examples
of
a
four-l^ged
straddle
in
the
general
case
,
with
each
1^
in
a
different
market
.
The
two-legged
straddle
Four-l^ged
arbitrage
is
the
basic
strat^y
of
the
wardiousing
business
.
Suppose
a
grain-
elevator
operator
normally
filis
one
of
his
two
bins
with
wheat
,
and
the
other
with
com
.
As
a
result
of
poor
weather
in
the
wheat-growing
regions
he
expects
the
wheat
/
com
spread
to
widai
.
Acting
on
his
insight
he
sells
his
com
(
initial
short
leg
)
and
filis
his
com
bin
with
wheat
(
initial
long
1^
).
When
his
expectation
is
fulfílled
and
the
wheat
/
com
spread
has
widened
,
he
sells
his
wheat
in
the
com
bin
(
terminal
short
1^
)
and
replaces
it
with
com
(
terminal
long
1^
).
Since
the
profitability
of
the
arbitrage
can
be
established
only
after
all
four
legs
are
Consider
the
vertical
arbitrage
of
the
producer
.
The
long
1^
x
of
his
straddle
is
in
the
producer
goods
market
and
the
short
1^
y
is
in
the
consumer
goods
market
,
where
x
is
the
input
and
y
the
output
of
his
production
line
.
This
is
called
a
two-legged
straddle
,
because
the
profit
from
the
arbitrage
can
be
calculated
already
when
the
first
two
legs
are
in
place
.
We
reduce
this
to
a
four-legged
straddle
by
adding
two
terminal
l^s
at
zero
pnces
(
so
that
the
addition
of
the
phantom
legs
does
not
afíect
the
profitability
of
the
arbitrage
).
The
significance
of
the
phantom
l^s
is
to
satisfy
the
requironents
of
double-entry
book-keeping
.
The
four
transactions
Laissez
-
Faire
3
/index.php?action=ajax&rs=GDMgetPage&rsargs[]=laissezfaire05_1_.pdf&rsargs[]=3
involved
are
:
placing
an
order
for
x
,
taking
an
order
for
y
,
taking
delivery
of
x
,
makíng
deliveiy
of
j^
.
They
correspond
to
the
four
l^s
,
respectively
,
of
a
straddle
:
(
1
)
the
initial
long
1^
x
,
(
2
)
the
initial
short
1^
>
'
,
(
3
)
the
terminal
short
leg
x
,
(
4
)
the
terminal
long
1^
>
^
.
the
opportunity
cost
of
buying
an
additional
unit
of
x
becomes
critical
to
the
marginal
consumer
of
x
.
He
is
the
first
consumer
to
refuse
to
buy
the
uptick
in
the
price
of
x
,
and
the
reference
is
to
his
opportunity
to
buy
a
substitute
instead
,
namely
,
the
consumer
good
x
\
The
one-legged
straddle
Consider
the
horizontal
arbitrage
of
the
producer
.
He
buys
the
favored
producer
good
x
(
his
present
input
)
while
he
refrains
from
buying
the
disfavored
one
y
(
his
former
input
).
This
creates
a
straddle
with
long
leg
x
and
short
leg
y
,
and
the
corresponding
spread
shows
the
profít
(
saving
)
that
arises
out
of
the
switch
from
y
to
X
.
This
is
called
a
one-legged
straddle
because
the
profít
from
the
arbitrage
can
be
calculated
already
when
the
single
long
leg
x
is
in
place
.
To
satisfy
the
requirements
of
double-entry
book-keeping
we
reduge
this
to
a
four-legged
straddle
by
adding
three
phantom
legs
.
The
four
transactions
involved
,
corresponding
to
the
four
legs
(
1
)
-
(
4
)
named
above
,
are
:
placing
an
order
for
x
,
cancelling
the
order
for
y
,
taking
delivery
of
x
,
and
getting
credit
for
the
cancelled
order
for^
,
respectively
.
The
terminal
legs
are
entered
at
zero
pnces
,
so
that
they
will
not
affect
the
profitability
of
the
arbitrage
.
We
are
now
ready
to
present
the
marginal
analysis
of
the
pnce
formation
of
consumer
goods
in
three
steps
:
the
formation
of
the
asked
pnce
,
the
formation
of
the
bid
pnce
,
and
the
closing
of
the
bid
/
asked
spread
.
Formation
of
the
asked
príce
As
noted
above
,
the
asked
pnce
is
the
outcome
of
competition
by
the
consumers
.
Li
more
details
,
the
asked
price
a
of
the
consumer
good
x
marks
the
point
where
All
consumers
of
x
are
doing
horizontal
arbitrage
all
the
time
:
they
constantly
shift
their
custom
.
Their
guiding
star
is
the
constellation
of
horizontal
spreads
.
As
a
result
of
the
competition
of
the
consumers
,
the
horizontal
spreads
will
widen
.
But
the
spreads
which
belong
to
the
one-l^ged
horizontal
straddles
with
long
leg
x
will
not
continué
to
widen
indefinitely
.
Their
widening
will
be
diecked
by
the
marginal
consumer
of
x
.
His
refusal
to
buy
x
,
and
his
buying
x'
instead
,
constitutes
an
opposite
horizontal
straddle
,
and
entering
it
will
stabilize
the
spread
.
Of
course
,
the
person
of
the
marginal
consumer
,
and
the
item
x'
he
considers
as
his
substitute
for
x
,
are
subject
to
change
without
notice
.
Whenever
another
consumer
takes
over
that
role
from
the
first
,
his
substitute
for
x
may
not
be
the
same
x'
;
it
could
be
x
".
Indeed
,
over
a
period
of
time
when
the
price
of
x
undergoes
a
change
,
hundreds
of
different
people
may
,
one
after
another
,
play
the
role
of
the
marginal
consumer
of
x
,
while
x'
sweeps
through
the
spectrum
of
possible
substitutos
for
x
.
This
picture
can
be
simplifíed
if
we
personify
the
marginal
consumer
of
x
,
and
think
of
him
as
a
figure
skater
skating
in
the
rink
of
consumer
goods
.
His
long
1^
is
anchored
to
X
,
while
his
short
1^
is
skating
through
the
possible
substitutos
of
x
.
This
,
then
,
is
the
mechanism
whereby
the
market
integrates
the
fragmented
power
over
the
price
of
X
that
resides
in
individual
Laissez
-
Faire
4
|
|